In the past decade, the accurate measurement of financial illiquidity risk has dramatically
gained in importance, almost geometrically in the past few years. This is obvious
when we look at the early example of the taxpayer-financed bail out of the
Russian-default-traumatized Long Term Capital Management (LTCM) hedge fund in 1998
and compare that with the recent March 2008 example of the Federal Reserve—JP Morgan
engineered electroshock of an already flat-lined mortgage portfolios-processing, Bear
Sterns, or the more diversified Lehman Brothers. The LTCM debacle was considered an
isolated incident. But recent history shows that it was just a predecessor of the current
series of collapses of major financial houses. Therefore, this study first looks at LTCM in
detail. It applied a trading strategy known as ‘convergence arbitrage’, which is based on
the idea that when two securities have the same theoretical price, because they have the
same return-risk profile, their market prices should eventually be the same. But this
convergence strategy ignores the observation that financial risk is a time-dependent or
long memory phenomenon and not a time-independent or no memory phenomenon to
which the usual central limit theory based on i.i.d. assumptions applies. Indeed, in the
summer of 1998, LTCM made a huge loss of $4 bn. This was triggered off when Russia suddenly and unexpectedly defaulted on its debt, which caused a flight to quality in the German bond market.
LTCM itself did not have a large exposure to Russian debt, but it tended to be long
illiquid German (off-the-run) bonds and the short corresponding liquid German
(on-the-run) bonds. The spreads between the prices of the illiquid bonds and the
corresponding liquid bonds widened sharply and immediately after the Russian default and
it suddenly imposed absolute illiquidity of the Russian debt. Credit default spreads also
increased and LTCM was highly leveraged, with a debt/equity ratio of close to 300, so that
the loss of profits on its spread hedges immediately translated into a very rapid vanishing
of its market valued equity and threatened bankruptcy. When it was unable to make its
projected ‘risk-free’ arbitrage profits, it experienced huge losses and there were margin calls
on its positions which it was unable to meet.
LTCM’s position was made more difficult by the fact that over a period of three years
many other hedge funds had also learned this game of “gigantically vacuuming pennies all
over the world” and implemented similar convergence arbitrage strategies.2 When LTCM
tried to liquidate part of its portfolio to meet its margin calls, by selling its illiquid
off-the-run bonds and by buying its liquid on-the-run bonds, other hedge funds faced with
similar problems did similar trades at the same time. Consequently, the price of the
on-the-run bonds rose sharply relative to the price of the off-the-run bonds. This caused
the illiquidity spreads to widen even further and to reinforce the original flight to quality.
Thus, the illiquidity problem was exacerbated and not alleviated by the crowding effect.
This was a clear example of a long-term illiquidity risk dependence accumulation that was
not foreseen by the time-independence assumptions of geometric Brownian motion
arbitrage models used by LTCM’s managers and partners, which assumes perfectly
competitive, generally liquid markets. |